Intertemporal choice and the magnitude effect
A robust finding in experiments on time preference is the magnitude effect: subjects tend to be more patient towards larger rewards. Using a calibration theorem, we argue against standard curvature-based explanations for the finding. We axiomatize a model of preferences over dated rewards that gener...
Saved in:
Published in | Games and economic behavior Vol. 72; no. 1; pp. 255 - 270 |
---|---|
Main Author | |
Format | Journal Article |
Language | English |
Published |
Duluth
Elsevier Inc
01.05.2011
Elsevier Academic Press |
Series | Games and Economic Behavior |
Subjects | |
Online Access | Get full text |
ISSN | 0899-8256 1090-2473 |
DOI | 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006 |
Cover
Abstract | A robust finding in experiments on time preference is the magnitude effect: subjects tend to be more patient towards larger rewards. Using a calibration theorem, we argue against standard curvature-based explanations for the finding. We axiomatize a model of preferences over dated rewards that generalizes the standard exponential discounting model by permitting the discount factor to depend on the reward being discounted. The model is shown to behaviorally subsume the hyperbolic discounting model as a special case. When embedded in a sequential bargaining game the model gives rise to multiple stationary subgame perfect equilibria. There may exist equilibria in which the first mover gets a smaller share despite also being the more patient player. |
---|---|
AbstractList | A robust finding in experiments on time preference is the magnitude effect: subjects tend to be more patient towards larger rewards. Using a calibration theorem, we argue against standard curvature-based explanations for the finding. We axiomatize a model of preferences over dated rewards that generalizes the standard exponential discounting model by permitting the discount factor to depend on the reward being discounted. The model is shown to behaviorally subsume the hyperbolic discounting model as a special case. When embedded in a sequential bargaining game the model gives rise to multiple stationary subgame perfect equilibria. There may exist equilibria in which the first mover gets a smaller share despite also being the more patient player. [PUBLICATION ABSTRACT] A robust finding in experiments on time preference is the magnitude effect: subjects tend to be more patient towards larger rewards. Using a calibration theorem, we argue against standard curvature-based explanations for the finding. We axiomatize a model of preferences over dated rewards that generalizes the standard exponential discounting model by permitting the discount factor to depend on the reward being discounted. The model is shown to behaviorally subsume the hyperbolic discounting model as a special case. When embedded in a sequential bargaining game the model gives rise to multiple stationary subgame perfect equilibria. There may exist equilibria in which the first mover gets a smaller share despite also being the more patient player. A robust finding in experiments on time preference is the magnitude effect: subjects tend to be more patient towards larger rewards. Using a calibration theorem, we argue against standard curvature-based explanations for the finding. We axiomatize a model of preferences over dated rewards that generalizes the standard exponential discounting model by permitting the discount factor to depend on the reward being discounted. The model is shown to behaviorally subsume the hyperbolic discounting model as a special case. When embedded in a sequential bargaining game the model gives rise to multiple stationary subgame perfect equilibria. There may exist equilibria in which the first mover gets a smaller share despite also being the more patient player. All rights reserved, Elsevier |
Author | Noor, Jawwad |
Author_xml | – sequence: 1 givenname: Jawwad surname: Noor fullname: Noor, Jawwad email: jnoor@bu.edu organization: Dept. of Economics, Boston University, 270 Bay State Road, Boston, MA 02215, United States |
BackLink | http://www.econis.eu/PPNSET?PPN=666181691$$DView this record in ZBW - Deutsche Zentralbibliothek für Wirtschaftswissenschaften http://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeegamebe/v_3a72_3ay_3a2011_3ai_3a1_3ap_3a255-270.htm$$DView record in RePEc |
BookMark | eNp9kUtr3DAUhUVJoZO0P6Crmm668uTK1sOiqxL6SAh0066FRr6a0WBLrqQJ5N9XZkIWWQRxdZH4ztFF55JchBiQkI8UthSouD5u97jbdlDPILYA4g3ZUFDQdkz2F2QDg1Lt0HHxjlzmfAQA3knYkPY2FEwF5yUmMzX2EL3FxoSxKQdsZrMPvpxGbNA5tOU9eevMlPHDU78if398_3Pzq73__fP25tt9azmF0gouGHeWsh5HIwfDUXBE5iQ163Jc9SitBclGq5hzDJziUuyssayX0vZX5MvZd0nx3wlz0bPPFqfJBIynrAehGNBe0Ep-fkEe4ymFOlyF6NALJlWF7s5QwgWtXpKfTXrUiLg3M-5QP-jeyK5uj7XqJ9LafK21L-sV57p-lz6UuZp9OpuhjcHnZzch6ntUqHUmeiZsijkndM8MBb2mpY-6pqXXtDQIXdOqGvlCY30xxcdQkvHTq8qvT_PUQB48Jp2tx2Bx9KlGpsfoX1H_B_OTraQ |
CitedBy_id | crossref_primary_10_1007_s10683_021_09723_w crossref_primary_10_1007_s40732_016_0165_4 crossref_primary_10_1016_j_seps_2024_101840 crossref_primary_10_1016_j_socec_2023_101999 crossref_primary_10_3390_math10224315 crossref_primary_10_2139_ssrn_2732626 crossref_primary_10_1016_j_jet_2020_105097 crossref_primary_10_1108_JM2_07_2023_0157 crossref_primary_10_1007_s11135_022_01581_9 crossref_primary_10_1287_mnsc_2017_3015 crossref_primary_10_2139_ssrn_2448695 crossref_primary_10_1002_rfe_1190 crossref_primary_10_1016_j_geb_2014_11_003 crossref_primary_10_2139_ssrn_2176784 crossref_primary_10_3982_ECTA16467 crossref_primary_10_3389_fams_2018_00055 crossref_primary_10_1007_s11135_024_01957_z crossref_primary_10_1287_mnsc_1110_1450 crossref_primary_10_1016_j_physa_2018_05_152 crossref_primary_10_1007_s40622_025_00428_0 crossref_primary_10_3982_ECTA16427 crossref_primary_10_1016_j_jmp_2013_04_002 crossref_primary_10_1257_aer_103_1_510 crossref_primary_10_1057_jors_2011_137 crossref_primary_10_3982_ECTA16050 crossref_primary_10_1007_s00712_013_0363_3 crossref_primary_10_1007_s11238_018_09683_3 crossref_primary_10_1111_cogs_12104 crossref_primary_10_1016_j_geb_2018_08_004 crossref_primary_10_2139_ssrn_3575208 |
Cites_doi | 10.1287/moor.20.2.381 10.1111/1468-0262.00158 10.2307/2526382 10.1257/002205102320161311 10.2307/2118482 10.1016/0165-1765(81)90067-7 10.1016/j.jet.2007.01.008 |
ContentType | Journal Article |
Copyright | 2010 Elsevier Inc. Copyright Academic Press May 2011 |
Copyright_xml | – notice: 2010 Elsevier Inc. – notice: Copyright Academic Press May 2011 |
DBID | AAYXX CITATION OQ6 DKI X2L 8BJ FQK JBE |
DOI | 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006 |
DatabaseName | CrossRef ECONIS RePEc IDEAS RePEc International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS) International Bibliography of the Social Sciences International Bibliography of the Social Sciences |
DatabaseTitle | CrossRef International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS) |
DatabaseTitleList | International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS) International Bibliography of the Social Sciences (IBSS) |
Database_xml | – sequence: 1 dbid: DKI name: RePEc IDEAS url: http://ideas.repec.org/ sourceTypes: Index Database |
DeliveryMethod | fulltext_linktorsrc |
Discipline | Psychology Mathematics |
EISSN | 1090-2473 |
EndPage | 270 |
ExternalDocumentID | 2319678301 eeegamebe_v_3a72_3ay_3a2011_3ai_3a1_3ap_3a255_270_htm 666181691 10_1016_j_geb_2010_06_006 S0899825610001053 |
Genre | Feature |
GrantInformation_xml | – fundername: NSF grantid: SES-0822927 |
GroupedDBID | --K --M -DZ -~X .~1 0R~ 1B1 1RT 1~. 1~5 29H 4.4 457 4G. 5GY 5VS 63O 7-5 71M 8P~ 9JO AABCJ AACTN AAEDT AAEDW AAFFL AAIAV AAIKJ AAKOC AALRI AAOAW AAPFB AAQFI AAQXK AAXUO ABFNM ABIVO ABJNI ABLJU ABMAC ABXDB ABYKQ ACDAQ ACGFS ACHQT ACRLP ACROA ADBBV ADEZE ADFGL ADFHU ADIYS ADMUD AEBSH AEKER AEYQN AFFNX AFKWA AFODL AFTJW AGHFR AGTHC AGUBO AGYEJ AHHHB AIEXJ AIIAU AIKHN AITUG AJBFU AJOXV AJWLA ALMA_UNASSIGNED_HOLDINGS AMFUW AMRAJ ASPBG AVWKF AXJTR AXLSJ AZFZN BEHZQ BEZPJ BGSCR BKOJK BLXMC BNTGB BPUDD BULVW BZJEE CAG COF CS3 DM4 DU5 EBS EFBJH EFLBG EJD EO8 EO9 EP2 EP3 F5P FDB FEDTE FGOYB FIRID FNPLU FYGXN G-2 G-Q GBLVA HMB HVGLF HZ~ IHE IXIXF J1W KOM LG5 LY4 M41 MO0 MVM N9A O-L O9- OAUVE OZT P-8 P-9 P2P PC. PQQKQ Q38 R2- RIG ROL RPZ SDF SDG SDP SEB SEE SES SEW SPCBC SSB SSF SSZ T5K TN5 UQL WUQ XPP XSW ZA5 ZMT ~G- AATTM AAXKI AAYWO AAYXX ABWVN ACRPL ACVFH ADCNI ADMHG ADNMO AEIPS AEUPX AFJKZ AFPUW AFXIZ AGCQF AGQPQ AGRNS AIGII AIIUN AKBMS AKRWK AKYEP ANKPU APXCP BNPGV CITATION SSH OQ6 DKI X2L 8BJ EFKBS FQK JBE ACLOT ~HD |
ID | FETCH-LOGICAL-c510t-65645fc143eda78a5e65ee4f71a1a1af593e7cc074dc94ff40f9576bcac4377c3 |
IEDL.DBID | AIKHN |
ISSN | 0899-8256 |
IngestDate | Sat Sep 27 23:26:54 EDT 2025 Sat Sep 06 22:31:32 EDT 2025 Thu Mar 28 07:20:29 EDT 2024 Sat Mar 08 16:09:43 EST 2025 Thu Apr 24 23:02:23 EDT 2025 Tue Jul 01 01:01:29 EDT 2025 Fri Feb 23 02:19:35 EST 2024 |
IsPeerReviewed | true |
IsScholarly | true |
Issue | 1 |
Keywords | Discounting D11 Hyperbolic discounting Calibration theorem Bargaining Magnitude effect Preference reversals |
Language | English |
License | https://www.elsevier.com/tdm/userlicense/1.0 |
LinkModel | DirectLink |
MergedId | FETCHMERGED-LOGICAL-c510t-65645fc143eda78a5e65ee4f71a1a1af593e7cc074dc94ff40f9576bcac4377c3 |
Notes | SourceType-Scholarly Journals-1 ObjectType-Feature-1 content type line 14 ObjectType-Article-2 content type line 23 |
PQID | 861836479 |
PQPubID | 33317 |
PageCount | 16 |
ParticipantIDs | proquest_miscellaneous_869401361 proquest_journals_861836479 repec_primary_eeegamebe_v_3a72_3ay_3a2011_3ai_3a1_3ap_3a255_270_htm econis_primary_666181691 crossref_primary_10_1016_j_geb_2010_06_006 crossref_citationtrail_10_1016_j_geb_2010_06_006 elsevier_sciencedirect_doi_10_1016_j_geb_2010_06_006 |
ProviderPackageCode | CITATION AAYXX |
PublicationCentury | 2000 |
PublicationDate | 2011-05-01 |
PublicationDateYYYYMMDD | 2011-05-01 |
PublicationDate_xml | – month: 05 year: 2011 text: 2011-05-01 day: 01 |
PublicationDecade | 2010 |
PublicationPlace | Duluth |
PublicationPlace_xml | – name: Duluth |
PublicationSeriesTitle | Games and Economic Behavior |
PublicationTitle | Games and economic behavior |
PublicationYear | 2011 |
Publisher | Elsevier Inc Elsevier Academic Press |
Publisher_xml | – name: Elsevier Inc – name: Elsevier – name: Academic Press |
References | Fishburn, Rubinstein (br0030) 1982; 23 Fredrick, Loewenstein, OʼDonoghue (br0040) 2002; 40 Harvey (br0050) 1995; 20 Loewenstein, Prelec (br0060) 1992; 57 Ok, Masatlioglu (br0070) 2007; 137 Ainslie (br0010) 1992 Thaler (br0100) 1981; 8 Pigou (br0080) 1920 Baucells, M., Heukamp, F., 2009. Probability and time trade-off. Mimeo. Rabin (br0090) 2000; 68 Thaler (10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0100) 1981; 8 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0020 Fishburn (10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0030) 1982; 23 Harvey (10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0050) 1995; 20 Ok (10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0070) 2007; 137 Ainslie (10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0010) 1992 Rabin (10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0090) 2000; 68 Loewenstein (10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0060) 1992; 57 Fredrick (10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0040) 2002; 40 Pigou (10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0080) 1920 |
References_xml | – volume: 57 start-page: 573 year: 1992 end-page: 598 ident: br0060 article-title: Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation publication-title: Quart. J. Econ. – volume: 40 start-page: 351 year: 2002 end-page: 401 ident: br0040 article-title: Time discounting and time preference: A critical review publication-title: J. Econ. Lit. – volume: 137 start-page: 214 year: 2007 end-page: 245 ident: br0070 article-title: A theory of (relative) discounting publication-title: J. Econ. Theory – year: 1920 ident: br0080 article-title: The Economics of Welfare – volume: 23 start-page: 677 year: 1982 end-page: 694 ident: br0030 article-title: Time preference publication-title: Int. Econ. Rev. – volume: 20 start-page: 381 year: 1995 end-page: 399 ident: br0050 article-title: Proportional discounting of future costs and benefits publication-title: Math. Oper. Res. – volume: 68 start-page: 1281 year: 2000 end-page: 1292 ident: br0090 article-title: Risk aversion and expected utility theory: A calibration theorem publication-title: Econometrica – reference: Baucells, M., Heukamp, F., 2009. Probability and time trade-off. Mimeo. – year: 1992 ident: br0010 article-title: Picoeconomics – volume: 8 start-page: 201 year: 1981 end-page: 207 ident: br0100 article-title: Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency publication-title: Econ. Letters – ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0020 – volume: 20 start-page: 381 issue: 2 year: 1995 ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0050 article-title: Proportional discounting of future costs and benefits publication-title: Math. Oper. Res. doi: 10.1287/moor.20.2.381 – year: 1920 ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0080 – volume: 68 start-page: 1281 issue: 5 year: 2000 ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0090 article-title: Risk aversion and expected utility theory: A calibration theorem publication-title: Econometrica doi: 10.1111/1468-0262.00158 – volume: 23 start-page: 677 issue: 3 year: 1982 ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0030 article-title: Time preference publication-title: Int. Econ. Rev. doi: 10.2307/2526382 – volume: 40 start-page: 351 issue: 2 year: 2002 ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0040 article-title: Time discounting and time preference: A critical review publication-title: J. Econ. Lit. doi: 10.1257/002205102320161311 – volume: 57 start-page: 573 issue: 2 year: 1992 ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0060 article-title: Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation publication-title: Quart. J. Econ. doi: 10.2307/2118482 – volume: 8 start-page: 201 year: 1981 ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0100 article-title: Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency publication-title: Econ. Letters doi: 10.1016/0165-1765(81)90067-7 – volume: 137 start-page: 214 issue: 1 year: 2007 ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0070 article-title: A theory of (relative) discounting publication-title: J. Econ. Theory doi: 10.1016/j.jet.2007.01.008 – year: 1992 ident: 10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006_br0010 |
SSID | ssj0005270 |
Score | 2.1136854 |
Snippet | A robust finding in experiments on time preference is the magnitude effect: subjects tend to be more patient towards larger rewards. Using a calibration... |
SourceID | proquest repec econis crossref elsevier |
SourceType | Aggregation Database Index Database Enrichment Source Publisher |
StartPage | 255 |
SubjectTerms | Bargaining Calibration theorem Discounting Discounting Magnitude effect Hyperbolic discounting Preference reversals Calibration theorem Bargaining Discounts Economic behaviour Economic models Equilibrium Experimenters Game theory Hyperbolic discounting Magnitude effect Preference reversals Preferences Rewards Studies |
Title | Intertemporal choice and the magnitude effect |
URI | https://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2010.06.006 http://www.econis.eu/PPNSET?PPN=666181691 http://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeegamebe/v_3a72_3ay_3a2011_3ai_3a1_3ap_3a255-270.htm https://www.proquest.com/docview/861836479 https://www.proquest.com/docview/869401361 |
Volume | 72 |
hasFullText | 1 |
inHoldings | 1 |
isFullTextHit | |
isPrint | |
link | http://utb.summon.serialssolutions.com/2.0.0/link/0/eLvHCXMwnV3NT9swFH8qLQd2QAw2tWOrcthpUmhTJ3ZyRN1QWTUO2xDcLNd5gaI2rWiLxIW_nfcSJ2ovHFCVWnLsxHrPfh9-vzwDfFek9VM5iP1IKemTRRz4RiDH4BWVcSiUKbJ9XsnRdfj7NrptwLD6FoZhlU72lzK9kNaupueo2VtOp71_HLAi_0byDjVZCWIPWgPS9nETWueX49HVFtKjODOO2_vcoQpuFjCvO5w4gBdHJeSOetpnn3S62tFTW3Zo6xGXaLfU0cURHDo70jsvh_oRGpgfw4c_dRLW1TEc1MLt-QT8YuvPJaKaeVRPEsIzeepRD29uGES0SdEr8R2f4Pri1__hyHdHJfiWFtXal5wUJrNk_GBqVGwilBFimKnA8C-LEoHKWrIXUpuEWRb2s4Q8jYk1ltihrPgMzXyRYxs8UthSGJKDok-swsCgDOMiz5dITDxJO9CvKKStyyPOx1nMdAUYe9BEVM1E1QVoTnbgR91lWSbReKtxuyR73ZQ8LLJDZBJ0IKwYoXcmiSb5_9YTTyumabdCVzqmZ3Lu_KQDXn2XlhbHS0yOiw03Sdj7lPTeYcHqekSIeGfmNP_1kxZGDejvmS42pqiY0sXlkquiSNP00_fr-Zf3jf4UDsp9bAZZfoXm-nGD38gQWk-6sHf2EnTddOdy_PdmTLU_x5evi8AEUg |
linkProvider | Elsevier |
linkToHtml | http://utb.summon.serialssolutions.com/2.0.0/link/0/eLvHCXMwnV1LT8MwDLZgQwIOiKc2nj1wQqq2kTZpj2gCjdcugMQtylIXhliZ9kDi32O3abVdOKCpi5QmbWQn9ufYdQDOFWn9RF5GfqiU9AkRd3wjkH3wisooEMrk2T77svcS3L2GryvQLb-F4bBKJ_sLmZ5La1fTctRsjYfD1hM7rMi-kbxDTShBrEI94EOta1C_ur3v9RciPfIz47i9zx1K52Ye5vWGAxfgxV4JuaSe1tgmHU6X9NQCDq1PcIx2QR3dbMOWw5HeVTHUHVjBbBc2H6skrNNd2KiE288e-PnWn0tE9elRPUkIz2SJRz28keEgonmCXhHfsQ8vN9fP3Z7vjkrwLS2qmS85KUxqCfxgYlRkQpQhYpCqjuFfGsYClbWEFxIbB2katNOYLI2BNZbYoaw4gFr2lWEDPFLYUhiSg6JNrMKOQRlEeZ4vEZtokDShXVJIW5dHnI-z-NRlwNiHJqJqJqrOg-ZkEy6qLuMiicZfjRsF2aumZGERDpFxpwlByQi9NEk0yf-_nnhUMk27FTrVET2Tc-fHTfCqu7S02F9iMvyac5OYrU9J7-3mrK5GhIhvZkTzX39rYdQl_f3QxWCKiiFdXI65Kgw1TT_9Phsd_m_0Z7Dee3580A-3_fsj2Cj2tDng8hhqs8kcTwgUzQanbtL_AnOPA5w |
openUrl | ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info%3Aofi%2Fenc%3AUTF-8&rfr_id=info%3Asid%2Fsummon.serialssolutions.com&rft_val_fmt=info%3Aofi%2Ffmt%3Akev%3Amtx%3Ajournal&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Intertemporal+choice+and+the+magnitude+effect&rft.jtitle=Games+and+economic+behavior&rft.au=Noor%2C+J&rft.date=2011-05-01&rft.issn=0899-8256&rft.volume=72&rft.issue=1&rft.spage=255&rft.epage=270&rft_id=info:doi/10.1016%2Fj.geb.2010.06.006&rft.externalDBID=NO_FULL_TEXT |
thumbnail_l | http://covers-cdn.summon.serialssolutions.com/index.aspx?isbn=/lc.gif&issn=0899-8256&client=summon |
thumbnail_m | http://covers-cdn.summon.serialssolutions.com/index.aspx?isbn=/mc.gif&issn=0899-8256&client=summon |
thumbnail_s | http://covers-cdn.summon.serialssolutions.com/index.aspx?isbn=/sc.gif&issn=0899-8256&client=summon |